The
Crisis in Health Care
Originally
published June, 1991
In two
recent columns in NEWSWEEK magazine, Robert J. Samuelson argued
persuasively that our educational system is failing because kids don't
have any necessity to study. Merely showing up for classes guarantees a
passing grade and thus graduation without ever having to think. The
number of colleges and universities has increased to the point that
competition for students (which directly translates into money) forces a
lowering of entrance requirements and standards. This economic
hyperinflation which results in devalued academic degrees and poorly
educated graduates is due to the fact that we don't demand
responsibility.
Samuelson
proposes the simple idea of requiring certification of grade level
competence by standardized examination before a student could receive
federal student aid. Thus would kids be given a powerful incentive to
learn. So, too, would the fakirs and frauds, as well as the simply
inept, among the teachers and administrators be exposed. Finally,
because they would not need to spend all their time in remediation, the
institutes of higher education would be free to ensure that the holder
of their degree was truly an educated person.
Just as
there is a crisis in the educational system, it is acknowledged that our
health care system is failing. Costs are escalating to astronomical
levels, while 34 million people have no health insurance. Government
programs have literally run out of money. In Illinois, for example,
pharmacists have not been paid by the state Medicaid program since March
and funds will not be available until the next fiscal year starts this
month. Those who have private insurance are finding more bureaucratic
roadblocks to collecting on claims. Consumers are losing confidence that
their insurance will stand behind them when it is needed. Meanwhile,
politicians come up with 30 second non-solutions and point the finger of
blame at their opponents.
Before
any solution to the problem can be proposed, indeed, before a solution
can even be formulated, it is necessary to define the shape and extent
of the problem. A reality check, if you will, to separate fact from
fantasy. Let's look, then, at some of the most important issues and see
how they can fit into a solution.
The cost of care
In 1989,
per capita health care spending was $2,354. This figure represents 12%
of the Gross National Product (GNPthat magical number of which
economists seem to be so fond and which is usually defined as "the
sum of all the goods and services produced.") The current
administration predicts that unless something is done to slow the growth
of health care costs, by the year 2030 they will account for 37% of GNP.
We suspect that this number is the result of a kind of Lake Woebegone
Effect. Garrison Keillor used to describe is mythical home town as a
place where all the children are above average. Inevitably, government
projections say that this or that system is taking an increasingly
larger section of the pie. If you add up all the totals, since each is
growing above average, the sum of all the sectors is larger than 100% of
the GNP (which is, of course, the sum of all the goods and service,
etc.; clearly an impossibility). The catch is that the prophecy is
weasled up with the disclaimer "if nothing is done...." It is
unimaginable to expect that politicians will leave anything alone for 40
years. They might not do the right thing, but they will do something, of
that you can be sure. Such predictions tend to be meaningless because
they only look at one segment and ignore market forces which still drive
our system. If they don't tell you what 25% of the GNP is going to take
the hit, it is obviously just a puff piece designed to sway votes.
The true
question is not how much will health care cost in such and such a year,
but, rather, how much are the people willing to spend either directly or
indirectly and how is that going to be financed. The politicians are
unwilling to answer this question but prefer to distort the facts to the
public. A Democratic health care plan, for example, would force
businesses to either enroll employees in health insurance plans or pay
into a fund which would purchase insurance for all Americans who are not
enrolled in a business plan. Supporters claim that such a plan would
save $78 billion over five years. It really doesn't because the $78
billion is still spent, but is paid by increased prices for everything
from shoe polish to toasters to automobiles.
The Great Insurance Scam
There is
no functional difference between buying an insurance policy and betting
the roulette wheel at Las Vegas. Both make fabulous profits for their
owners by paying back at less than the actual odds of an event
occurring. A roulette wheel pays 36 to 1 for a single number, but
because of the 0 and 00, the odds of any single number winning are
actually 38 to 1. The difference goes to the house and makes millions
(unless you are Donald Trump but that's a different story). Insurance
companies hire scores of actuaries (people who calculate the actual odds
of an event occurring) and pay off the unfortunate at a multiple of the
premium less than the true odds (Ed.
note: Insurance does pay off at true odds, but the odds are ture only
over the anticipated lifetime of the insured but not the anticipated
term of the insurance. In effect, this is rigging the odds.)
The wheel in Las Vegas can be rigged with magnets, although that is
illegal. Insurance companies can rig their wheel, too, although they
usually do so legally. For example, many health policies that include
prescription drug coverage will exclude birth control pills and smoking
deterrent gum. Although the real costs of a pregnancy or a case of lung
cancer are considerably higher than the price of the prescriptions, the
exclusion is in place because the insurance company prefers a high
future expense to a high current expense (The
insurance company makes its profit on the future value of the premium.
That is, on the return that the invested premium makes before they have
to pay it back--the longer they can hold the money, the higher their
profits)
Their logic is they know what the prescription costs and although they
know the odds over the long haul, the woman may not get pregnant or the
smoker may not develop lung cancer before the worker changes jobs and
the policy is terminated (in which case the insurance company wins)
Because Americans change employers as frequently as they do, it is not
in the insurance company's interest to promote programs which reduce
long term health costs.
For
another example of the disparity between the insurance industry's words
(their advertisements) and their actions, consider what would happen if
automobile policies contained the following: "All claims against
this policy will be null and void if the insured driver was found to
have a blood alcohol level of 0.05ppm (1/2 the legal level for
intoxication)." Drivers would be aware that they could be
financially ruined if they were involved in an accident with alcohol on
their breath. This would be a powerful incentive to not drink and drive
and the losses due to alcohol related accidents would drop like a rock.
Because premiums would be lower to reflect the improved safety,
insurance companies would suffer decreased cash flow, the worst thing
next to a slump in profits. That is why we keep killing ourselves on the
highway at such an alarming rate.
Great Expectations
One
reason used by the politicians to justify their caution in moving on
public health questions is that the public wants quality health care but
doesn't want to hear about the costs. That argument is, however, not
valid. Obviously, we want as much as possible for free. However, if the
public can accept that two cars in every garage and a chicken in every
pot does not mean a Rolls-Royce Silver Spur and a Ferrari Testarossa and
Coq Au Vin in bone china with crystal and silver, it seems reasonable to
assume the public's expectations about health care can include
comprehensive, basic care without some, or all, of the bells and
whistles.
It is
the responsibility of those entrusted with governance to provide the
leadership which sets the national agenda on a course which is fair,
compassionate and affordable. Instead we have such examples as last
year's Pryor bill which, you may recall, we covered in detail. The
selling point of this legislation was "...it will enable the poor
to afford quality health care. They won't have to endure second class
service." It does, in fact, no such thing but is merely an indirect
tax (through higher prescription prices and hospital costs) to help
reduce the government's cost of the Medicaid program. It is such
vagueness and deceit which fuels the public's demand for "Quality
health care for all" without any idea of what that means. Such
slogans, then, become fodder for the aspirations of the political
opportunists and justification for their inaction.
Designing a Health Care System
It is,
surprisingly, not too difficult to design a health care system that
meets the requirements of fairness, compassion and affordability. It
only requires political debate based on truth and honesty (maybe for
some that would be difficult). Let's point out in one possible direction
and see where it leads.
The
primary question should be what is the role of the government in any
health care system? The options range from a pure market driven system
where the level of care you receive is directly proportional to the
thickness of your wallet, to pure socialized medicine which, experience
has shown, lacks the innovation and vitality provided by the spark of
capitalism. If, however, the function of government is to provide for
the common good, it argues strongly that, just as with public safety and
defense, the government should bear the primary responsibility of
ensuring basic service to all. There are three mechanisms by which this
goal can be accomplished: Changing the focus of health care, setting
clear priorities and providing incentives for individual change.
Changing the Focus of Health Care
The
current health care system operates on the philosophy that when some
health care problem occurs, all the stops may be pulled out to treat
that problem. Diagnostic methods and treatments are beyond what could
reasonably called exotic. If you've ever wondered why it's easier to
find a magnetic resonance imaging (MRI) device than it is a physician
who will sit down with you for 15 minutes to listen to you, the answer
is quite simple. One gets paid, the other doesn't. This is a direct
result of the dominance of the private insurance system. As we've seen,
the goal of insurance companies is not to encourage better health, but
to increase the profit line. This is done by postponing current expenses
(such as preventative services) to minimize them in favor of future
expenses (such as acute treatment). From a business point of view, this
makes sense, but from the aspect of improving public health, it is
counter-productive. The emphasis should be placed on prevention and
early detection so that heroic and technologically complex (and
inevitably costly) treatments are less frequently required. The current
fee system encourages physicians to specialize. Consequently, our most
pressing shortage is among general practitioners, the physician the
patient should see first and the one who can work with the patient to
help develop a healthier lifestyle. Because of the current fee system,
these physicians must now run their patients through the office like
cattle in order to generate enough volume to maintain their income. By
shifting the fee structure to emphasize the intellectual skills, such as
diagnoses and counseling, as opposed to the merely technological (which
is part of the reason that any visit to an office requires a whole
battery of lab tests, a good money maker), physicians could spend more
time with their patients and help get the problems straightened out
before they occurred or when they were only minor.
The way
to accomplish this is to break the stranglehold of the private insurers.
Although the industry will argue that it is highly regulated, that
regulation is in the form of state agencies. Because the industry's
business is usually conducted in interstate commerce, those agencies are
usually only paper tigers. The first step required would be the
establishment of a federal agency to replace the state agencies under
the concept that health insurance should be treated as a regulated
utility. In that way, the insurance companies could be guaranteed a
profit (like an electric generating company), in return for ceding the
policy making function to a more health oriented view. Within such a
system, insurance companies could increase their profits by streamlining
and improving their administrative functions.
Setting Priorities
Currently,
most third party programs (insurance or government programs such as VA,
Medicare or Medicaid, etc.) will pay for almost any treatment as long as
there is money left in the kitty. When the money runs out, either rates
go up or the payments stop as we've seen in the case of the Illinois
Medicaid pharmacy program. There is little or no sense of priority
except who's the first to present the bill.
If you
are buying a car, for example, you would not pick out a model and then
start adding the options alphabetically until you hit your monetary
limit. Rather, you would rank the options in the order of desirability
and then choose them on that basis. The same approach should be done for
the public financing of health care. The first step is to admit there is
a limit on how much can be spent and then determine what the amount is.
This is determined in the political debate over the level and type of
taxation the citizens are willing to pay. The priorities on spending can
then be determined. It is not difficult to list every disease or
condition that can be treated along with the estimated associated costs.
This list is then ranked in order of importance. For example, do we
consider the treatment of broken bones more important than acne? Some
choices like that are easy, but some calls are closer. Which is more
important, a heart transplant or prenatal care? Who stands ahead of whom
in the line for funding, the cancer victim of the person with diabetes?
or AIDS? or a stroke? The choices may not always be easy but they can be
done. At that point, then, you start at the top of the list adding up
the associated costs. When the running total equals the amount of money
available, you draw a line. Above the line there is full coverage, below
it there is none.
Although
it may seem unfair to someone who is caught below the line, by using
such criteria as cost effectiveness and occurrence rates to select the
priorities, funding will go to helping the most people most effectively
within the framework of fixed available resources. Such a method also
shows what incremental increases in funding can buy and lets the public
decide if tax increases would be worth it.
Incentives for Personal Change
The
present system does little to encourage people to live healthier lives.
Although cigarette smoking is one of the greatest single causes of
serious disease, the government still subsidizes tobacco growers (Why
not pay them not to grow tobacco?) and offers no incentives for people
to quit smoking. Pressure from non-smokers rights groups have had an
effect and there are warnings on cigarette packages, but where are the
economic incentives that would reduce the smoking rate? Examples could
range from full coverage of smoking cessation programs to economic
disincentives to continue smoking such as loss or reduction of benefits
for treatment of lung cancer in smokers or higher taxes on cigarettes to
cover the health costs. Five dollars a pack (or an equivalent amount for
cigars and other tobacco products) that was earmarked for smoking
related diseases would help reduce the funding crunch, and provide a
good reason for people to stop smoking. As we mentioned earlier, the
simple addition of no insurance coverage for alcohol related auto
accidents would greatly diminish this problem without restricting
people's freedom. Mammography, for example, is encouraged for women, yet
insurance premiums don't differentiate between women who are compliant
and those who are not. Such a differential would increase compliance and
decrease subsequent health costs. People respond to economic incentives
better than they do to health warnings. It makes sense, then, to
encourage healthy behavior by making those choices economically
advantageous to the individual.
Final Thoughts
The
crisis in the health care system can be remedied. The solution, however
will not be maintaining the status quo and pouring more money down a
sinkhole. The responsibility for public health must be debated and
defined. Priorities must be determined and the individual must be made a
part of the system. As in the case of education that Samuelson presents,
the answers are relatively easy, it's only the questions that are hard.
What's needed is leadership with the courage to ask those questions. |